Themes > News Analysis       Print           
Print this article
Cotton and International Trade: Unfair Prices for the Developing World
Ranja Sengupta

In the post WTO era, ever since agriculture was opened up to free global trade, world prices of cotton have witnessed a sharp and steady decline. Despite the avowal to cut protection in agriculture, the post WTO era has not seen any reduction in protection that is being given to farmers in rich developed countries like the US and the European Union. The subsidies given by the US to its cotton farmers have largely been accepted to be the reason for the spectacular decline in cotton prices at a global level.

The reason for this is that since the government provides a large range of domestic support, US cotton farmers increase their production unlimitedly and in much excess of domestic demand. This excess is then dumped in the international market, which makes the world cotton supply much larger than demand and brings down cotton prices. This is possible since the US has various export promotion programmes like credit promotion and other direct payments for making US cotton globally competitive, which, though disguised as non-subsidies, actually help to dump this surplus in the international market. Some of it is given as compensation to US farmers if their actual price is higher than the world price (See step 2 payments in the box below). This obviously encourages the US producer to dump a huge supply on the international market. Not surprisingly, world prices have declined steadily since 1995 and reached a 29 year low in 2001.

While Cotton prices have declined by more than 60 percent since 1995, U.S. subsidies to its 25,000 cotton farmers reached 3.9 billion dollars in 2001-02, double the level of subsidies in 1992. Interestingly, the value of subsidies provided by American taxpayers to the cotton barons of Texas and elsewhere in 2001 exceeded the market value of output of cotton by around 30 per cent. In addition, this subsidy is provided to only the richest 10% of US farmers who get 73% of the total cotton subsidies. The rest of the cotton farmers in America hardly benefit from these subsidies. This actually shows that US subsidies, though largely domestic, is actually for the benefit of the export market.

BOX: Provisions that are given in US Law to protect its cotton farmers

 
Cotton Competitiveness: Provisions in US Law

These are "provisions added by the Food, Agriculture, Conservation, and Trade Act of 1990 to the cotton program designed to keep U.S. cotton price competitive in domestic and export markets. Sometimes referred to as the "three-step competitiveness" provisions. Step 1 is the discretionary authority for USDA to reduce the adjusted world price (used in the cotton marketing assistance loan program) when world prices are declining to near the adjusted world price, but U.S. prices are higher than world prices. Though rarely used, the Step 1 adjustment is intended to make marketing loans more effective in keeping U.S. cotton globally competitive. Step 2 payments, sometimes referred to as the "user marketing certificate program," are made to U.S. cotton users and exporters when U.S. prices are higher than world prices. Step 2 payments are intended to bridge price gap and keep U.S. cotton competitive. Step 3 mandates the opening of a "special import quota" when the differential between the higher U.S. price for cotton and the lower price for foreign cotton extends for a specified length of time. Its purpose is to allow imports to enter, acting to lower U.S. prices to bring them more in line with world prices. Step 3 quotas were in effect in April-May 1995, from late October 1995 through early May 1997, and were triggered in late February 1999. A step 3 quota cannot be established if a limited global quota for upland cotton is in effect, which operates differently and is triggered when other price conditions are met."

Source: http://www.webref.org/agriculture/c/cotton_competitiveness_provision.htm

World Production of Cotton
Between 1998-99 and 2002-03 the US has increased its production at an annual rate of 5.45% (Table 1). It reached its peak in 2001-02, producing a staggering 20, 303 thousand bales of cotton. Interestingly, its surplus of production over domestic demand has also increased steadily from 3,517 thousand bales in 1998-99 to 9,909 thousand bales in 2002-03. This is close to a three-fold increase in surplus levels over a span of just 4 years and represents a 29.56 % annual growth rate. Stocks show a much lower growth rate of 8.70% per annum. This is not surprising since the huge production is dumped into the export market. World production also shows a huge increase between 1998-99, and 2001-02 when it reached peak levels. From a figure of 85, 298 thousand bales in 1998-99, it went up to 98,463 bales in 2001-02.

Table 1: World Cotton Production, Consumption, Export, Imports and Stocks (1000 480 lb bales)

  1998/99 1999/00 2000/01 2001/02 2002/03
Estimate
2003/04
Forecast
Share in World Total
acc. to
198/99 Figure
Share in World
Total
acc. to
2002/03
Annual Average
Growth Rate
(1998-99 to
2002-03)

Production

China
20,700
17,600
20,300
24,400
22,600
27,00
24.27
25.69
2.22
United States
13,198
16,968
17,188
20,303
17,209
17,104
16.32
19.56
5.45
India
12,883
12,180
10,931
12,300
10,600
12,000
15.10
12.05
-4.76
Pakistan
6,300
8,600
8,200
8,300
7,800
8,500
7.39
8.86
5.48
Uzbekistan
4,600
5,180
4,400
4,900
4,700
4,500
5.39
5.34
0.54
Brazil
2,391
3,216
4,312
3,518
3,800
4,250
2.80
4.32
12.28
Turkey
3,860
3,634
3,600
3,975
4,134
4,200
4.53
4.70
1.73
Others
20,646
20,121
19,776
20,767
17,146
17,821
24.20
19.49
-4.54
World
85,298
87,499
88,707
98,463
87,989
95,375
100.00
100
0.78

Use

China
18,700
21,300
23,500
26,000
28,900
30,200
22.09
29.56
11.50
India
12,620
13,547
13,544
13,275
13,300
13,500
14.91
13.60
1.32
Pakistan
7,000
7,650
8,100
8,500
9,200
9,400
8.27
9.41
7.07
United States
10,401
10,194
8,862
7,696
7,300
6,600
12.29
7.47
-8.47
Turkey
4,600
5,600
5,167
6,150
6,300
6,450
5.43
6.44
8.18
Brazil
3,774
4,236
4,200
3,800
3,500
3,700
4.46
3.58
-1.87
Indonesia
2,200
2,000
2,450
2,300
2,300
2,300
2.60
2.35
1.12
Other
25,345
26,430
26,349
26,660
26,967
27,011
29.94
27.58
1.56
World
84,640
90,957
92,172
94,381
97,767
99,161
100.00
100
3.67

Imports

China
359
117
241
449
3,200
3,000
1.44
10.37
72.79
Turkey
1,139
2,400
1,750
2,868
2,100
2,400
4.57
6.80
16.53
Indonesia
2,323
2,076
2,650
2,356
2,250
2,300
9.33
7.29
-0.80
Thailand
1,211
1,706
1,584
2,057
1,950
1,950
4.86
6.32
12.65
Mexico
1,422
1,813
1,865
2,065
2,300
1,750
5.71
7.45
12.77
India
508
1,600
1,567
1,950
1,400
1,700
2.04
4.54
28.84
Russian Federation
850
1,600
1,650
1,850
1,700
1,700
3.41
5.51
18.92
Other
17,088
17,065
15,266
16,020
15,962
15,658
68.63
51.72
-1.69
World
24,900
28,377
26,573
29,615
30,862
30,458
100.00
100
5.51

Exports

United States
4,298
6,750
6,740
11,000
11,900
11,800
18.16
38.96
28.99
Uzbekistan
3,812
4,100
3,400
3,400
3,500
3,300
16.11
11.46
-2.11
Australia
3,040
3,209
3,904
3,101
2,600
1,650
12.84
8.51
-3.83
Greece
964
1,080
1,424
1,000
1,300
1,150
4.07
4.26
7.76
Brazil
23
12
315
674
475
1,000
0.10
1.56
113.18
Mali
950
900
575
925
850
950
4.01
2.78
-2.74
Burkina Faso
525
520
520
650
725
800
2.22
2.37
8.40
Other
10,056
10,755
9,711
8,302
9,194
9,360
42.49
30.10
-2.22
World
23,668
27,326
26,589
29,052
30,544
30,010
100.00
100
6.58

Ending Stocks

China
23,033
17,758
14,351
12,858
9,008
8,558
47.89
23.95
-20.92
United States
3,939
3,915
6,000
7,448
5,500
4,300
8.19
14.62
8.70
India
4,750
4,913
3,773
4,688
3,338
3,488
9.88
8.87
-8.44
Brazil
1,741
2,393
2,968
2,415
2,915
2,865
3.62
7.75
13.75
Pakistan
1,711
2,696
2,646
3,261
2,436
2,311
3.56
6.48
9.23
Turkey
593
827
882
1,450
1,259
1,209
1.23
3.35
20.71
Australia
2,085
2,309
2,095
2,211
1,286
921
4.33
3.42
-11.38
Other
10,245
10,756
9,935
12,855
11,877
10,640
21.30
31.57
3.76
World
48,097
45,567
42,650
47,186
37,619
34,292
100.00
100.00
-5.96
US :
Production -Use
3,517
6,774
8,326
12,607
9,909
10,504
-
-
29.56
Data Source: www.fas.usda.gov

A look at table 1 shows that the US has increased its export market share drastically between 1998-99 and 2002-03. From a share of 18.16% in 1998-99, America’s share in world exports jumped to 38.96 % in 2002-03. This represents a huge annual average growth rate of 28.99% between these two years. Obviously, nudged on by its subsidy programme, US exports have been able to keep pace with its surplus growth rate.

Only in the last two years does the US show a decline in production and a subsequent decline in World production has generated a surplus of use over production, resulting in an increase in world prices.

Global Prices of cotton and the US
In 2001-02, global prices were around 42 cents per pound, the fourth year in succession that they were below the long-term average of 72 cents per pound (Table 2). Even the most efficient producers are now operating at a loss, unable to cover the costs of production. Marketing projections by the International Cotton Advisory Committee (ICAC) suggest that prices will remain chronically depressed in the foreseeable future. Forecasts point to a modest recovery in 2003, but prices look likely to remain at between 50-60 cents per pound until 2015 if present conditions continue.

Table 2 and Chart 1 show the spectacular decline in the Cotlook Index A, the indicator for the global prices of cotton. The annual indices according to both calendar and crop year (the latter is the more relevant timeframe) reflect this pattern. However, only in the last one-two years have there been some improvement in the global prices of cotton. That is largely because of the fact that due to the rock-bottom price in 2001-02, global stocks had been drawn down subsequently. But unless the subsidies are cut soon, the imbalance in the world market will continue.

Table 2: Cotlook A Index (in cents/pound)

Year
Jan
Feb
Mar
Apr
May
Jun
Jul
Aug
Sep
Oct
Nov
Dec
Calendar
Year
Crop
Year
1991
83.58
85.17
84.00
83.40
84.35
83.76
80.72
73.01
70.09
67.83
63.39
61.69
76.75
62.96
1992
59.20
56.27
55.46
58.51
60.65
64.26
65.18
59.55
56.23
52.91
52.77
54.30
57.94
57.73
1993
57.34
60.60
61.45
61.05
61.14
58.48
54.40
55.20
54.79
55.14
59.53
58.09
70.76
1994
69.21
80.65
81.82
83.94
86.10
85.51
81.86
76.67
75.10
74.07
77.58
87.17
79.97
92.72
1995
95.62
100.94
110.50
113.76
115.74
-
-
85.06
91.18
91.14
89.19
87.92
98.11
85.59
1996
86.20
85.05
83.21
82.78
82.65
82.96
79.74
76.34
75.36
75.37
76.07
79.22
80.41
78.60
1997
79.88
80.43
80.61
78.89
79.35
80.58
81.14
81.17
79.56
77.54
77.20
74.39
79.23
72.13
1998
71.24
68.76
68.45
65.04
64.48
68.32
69.37
68.13
65.87
60.85
56.71
56.03
65.27
58.88
1999
55.78
56.16
56.73
57.88
59.82
58.30
54.34
50.98
49.35
47.44
46.13
44.21
53.09
52.84
2000
47.77
53.73
57.46
58.72
60.50
59.47
58.38
60.86
61.65
60.90
63.98
-
58.49
56.42
2001
64.13
60.40
54.56
51.16
49.97
47.46
45.57
43.35
41.26
37.22
37.88
42.87
47.99
41.85
2002
43.42
42.81
42.04
41.38
39.93
43.48
46.59
49.43
49.02
49.56
52.24
55.18
46.26
55.75
2003
56.71
58.54
61.01
60.78
57.80
58.50
60.21
60.50
-
-
-
-
59.26
60.50
Source: Cotlook, Ltd., Liverpool, England. Quality 31-3-35.
 

Since it has managed to bring in such a large supply, the subsidies given by the US government has brought down international prices considerably. Consequently, after 1995 when the Agreement on Agriculture came into effect, global prices continued to fall reaching the lowest ever level in 29 years in 2001. It is not surprising, and only goes to prove the trade distorting nature of US subsidies, that this all-time-low in global prices coincide with the highest level of US subsidies in 2001-02. The subsidies managed to bring the largest ever supply of cotton by US farmers to the export market around 2001 and 2002.

This price pattern is ironical considering agricultural prices were supposed to increase after the Agreement on Agriculture. A less protected international agricultural market and the removal of subsidies by the developed countries were supposed to improve cotton prices and therefore improve the lot of poor farmers in poorer countries. However, the reality turned out to be rather different.

The Developing World
Estimates by the International Cotton Advisory Committee (ICAC), using its World Textile Demand Model, indicate that the withdrawal of American cotton subsidies would raise cotton prices by 11 cents per pound, or by 26 per cent.

The refusal to cut cotton subsidies by the US has adversely affected the condition in many developing or least developed countries, which are exporters of cotton. The government of India puts its losses at $1.3 billion, Argentina at over $ 1 billion, and Brazil at $ 640 million in 2001-02. However, countries located in Africa, especially Benin, Burkina Faso, Chad and Mali, who depend heavily on cotton exports for their economic conditions, have been hit the hardest by the secular decline in prices. In 11 countries in Africa, cotton export earnings bring in one fourth of all export revenue. In the four above-mentioned African countries, 30 per cent of total export earnings and over 60 per cent of earnings from agricultural exports come from cotton. According to Oxfam, U.S. cotton subsidies are destroying livelihoods in Africa by encouraging over-production and product dumping.

According to an Oxfam Report (2001), costs of production for one pound of cotton are three times higher in the US than in Burkina Faso. Other major producers like Brazil also have far lower production costs. In spite of this, the US has expanded production in the midst of the price slump. Obviously cotton subsidies help them to increase production unlimitedly, and then dump that higher production in world markets.

Other countries have consequently suffered as a result of both lower prices for exports and loss of world market share. While the US improved its share gradually to a massive 40% of the world market, other major exporters who could not subsidies their exports suffered a decline. Uzbekistan’s share dropped from 16.11% to 11.46%, and that of Mali from 4.01% to 2.78% between 1998-99 and 2002-03. In fact this decline had started even earlier. Burkina Faso’s share increased marginally but it lost out in real terms due to the steady decline in global prices of cotton.

Only a sharp reversal in the policies of US can better the lot of cotton farmers in the south. But given the tone at Cancun, that will be a difficult, if not impossible, achievement for the developing and

September 29, 2003.


© International Development Economics Associates 2003